I hope you enjoy this guest post contributed by Jon Hartley.
As the Federal Reserve moves closer to normalizing monetary
policy and moving toward a federal funds rate “lift-off” date, I’ve created MonetaryPolicyRules.org, a new
website that provides up-to-date interactive graphs of popular monetary policy
rules.
Since the federal funds rate has hit the zero lower bound, Taylor
rules have received a lot of criticism in large part because many Taylor rules have
prescribed negative nominal interest rates during and after the global
financial crisis. Chicago Fed President (and prominent monetary policy scholar)
Charles Evans stated
about the Taylor Rule that “The rule completely breaks down during the
Great Recession and its aftermath”.
The discretionary versus rules-based monetary policy debate
endures, most recently with the Federal Reserve Accountability and Transparency
Act being introduced in Congress, followed by a series of dueling Wall Street Journal op-eds by John
Taylor and Alan
Blinder. Rather
than thinking about Taylor rules as a prescription for monetary policy (in a normative economics sense), what has
been left out of the discussion is how Taylor rules can accurately be a
description of monetary policy regimes (in a positive economics sense) even if the
central bank does not explicitly follow a stated rule.
Tim Duy has accurately pointed out in a recent
post that using the GDP and inflation forecasts also provided by the FOMC
for 2014 through 2017 (and beyond), no traditional monetary policy rule
captures the median of the current fed fund rate forecasts (commonly known as
the “dot plots” released by the Federal Reserve on a quarterly basis as part of
their Delphic forward guidance) which are considerably lower than either the Taylor (1993),
Taylor (1999), Mankiw (2001), or Rudebusch
(2009) rules would estimate.
What’s also worth noting is that in the early to mid-2000’s the
federal funds rate was considerably lower than what any of the above classic
monetary policy rules would estimate. This in large part is because all of
these rules were estimated using data from the “Great Moderation” of the
1990’s, which was then led by a very different Federal Reserve than we have
today (note those rules fit the federal funds effective rate data very
accurately during the 1990’s).
Source: Tim Duy |
The real question is how can we estimate a monetary policy
rule that describes the Bernanke-Yellen Fed, while also addressing the problem of
the zero lower bound for nominal interest rates?
One interesting idea that has gained some popularity
recently is the idea of measuring a “shadow federal funds rate” (originally hypothesized
by Fisher Black in a 1995
paper, published just before his death, which uses fed funds futures rates
and an affine term structure model to back out a negative spot rate). The idea
nicely estimates the potential effects of quantitative easing on long-term
rates while the federal funds rate is at the
zero lower bound (and for that reason I’ve included the Wu-Xia
(2014) shadow fed funds rate on the site). With the shadow fed funds rate
in hand, one can now estimate a monetary policy rule with a standard OLS
regression. One issue with this methodology is how there is a lack of consensus
around what to use as input data for a shadow rate which can give you very
different results (Khan and
Hakkio (2014) observed that the Wu-Xia (2014)
shadow fed funds rate looks remarkably different from the rate calculated by Krippner
(2014)).
Wu-Xia (2014) and Krippner (2014) Shadow Federal Funds Rates (in %)Source: Khan and Hakkio (2014), Federal Reserve Board of Governors, Krippner (2014), Wu-Xia (2014) |
One other solution to the problem of estimating a monetary
policy rule at the zero lower bound is an econometric one. Fortunately, we have
Tobit regressions in our econometric toolbox (originally developed by James
Tobin (1958)) which allow us to estimate Taylor rules
while censoring data at the zero lower bound.
In my Taylor rule that is estimated with federal funds rate from
the Bernanke-Yellen period, censoring data at the zero lower bound using a
Tobit regression, I use both y/y core CPI inflation and unemployment. In
another version, I use the Fed’s new Labor Market Conditions Index (LMCI) as a
labor market indicator though both yield relatively similar results*. Importantly,
these estimates indicate that the Bernanke-Yellen Fed puts a much higher weight
on the output/unemployment gap than the Mankiw (2001) rule estimated
with data from the Greenspan period.
Tobit Taylor Rule
Using Unemployment Rate and Core CPI as Inputs:
Federal Funds Target Rate = max{0, -0.43 + 1.2*(Core CPI y/y
%) – 2.6*(Unemployment Rate-5.6)}
Using unemployment and inflation forecast data from the latest
Federal Reserve FOMC meeting’s Survey of Economic Projections, I input
these data as inputs into the Tobit Rule and Mankiw (2001) Rule. Matching these
federal funds rate targets implied by the rules with the median federal funds
forecasts provided by both the
Federal Reserve “dot plots” and the Survey of
Primary Dealers (note: the expected Fed Funds rate path from Survey of
Primary Dealers has significantly fallen below the Fed dot plot Fed Funds rate
path as noted by Christensen
(2014)). Unfortunately, we do not have precise data on which dots belong to
which Fed officials (otherwise, we could try to construct a Taylor rule for
each Fed president and board member). Compared to the Mankiw (2001) rule, the estimated
Tobit rule much better matches the median forecasts provided by the dot plots
and the Survey of Primary Dealers.
Federal Reserve
Forward Guidance/Survey of Primary Dealers Fed Funds Rate Forecasts versus
Tobit Rule and Mankiw (2001) Rule Using Fed Unemployment and CPI Forecasts
Janet Yellen has spoken
fondly of the Taylor
(1999) rule in the past as she has previously stated in a 2012
speech that “[John] Taylor himself continues to prefer his original rule,
which I will refer to as the Taylor (1993) rule. In my view, however, the later
variant--which I will refer to as the Taylor (1999) rule--is more consistent
with following a balanced approach to promoting our dual mandate.”
It is no surprise that the Tobit rule estimated with more
recent data comes much closer to accurately describing the Fed’s forward
guidance than the Taylor (1993)
rule. However, what is really interesting is that the Tobit Rule is also much closer to describing the Fed’s current
forward guidance than the Taylor
(1999) rule, which remains far off.
Footnote:
A previous post on this blog astutely points out that correlation of 12-month changes in LMCI with 12-month changes in the unemployment rate is -0.96, suggesting that “the LMCI doesn’t tell you anything that the unemployment rate wouldn’t already tell you”. While the economists who developed the LMCI list on the Fed’s website the correlations of 12-month changes (which tell you the tendency of large 12-month figures moving together), I would argue that this is accurate of long-term labor market trends, while the correlations of monthly changes with the LMCI is a more accurate representation of the extent the measures move together in small short-term labor market movements. Doing so indicates that the monthly level of the LMCI has a -0.82 correlation with the unemployment rate, suggesting that the LMCI is not completely redundant in short-term labor market movements, incorporating some parts of the mixed economic narrative told by dampening wage growth, low labor force participation, and high amount of underemployed part-timers.
This comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDeleteThe mba assignments help is for those who cannot write their thesis well so now they can take help.
ReplyDeleteyeezy 350
ReplyDelete